Should the federal government dictate urban policy? This seems to be the default assumption among many Republicans and Democrats, for pet issues ranging from housing to infrastructure to immigration. But for those who care about cities, this approach may be wrong for two reasons. The first is that the federal government redirects tax revenue away from cities and into less productive rural areas, amounting to a raw deal for major metros. The second is that even when cities do receive federal funding, it is often wildly out of step with their needs. These problems are particularly pronounced for today's topic, transportation.
Let's examine this first problem, of cities receiving less money from the federal government than they put in. As Nicole Gelinas once noted for City Journal, New York City between 1981 and 2005 got 85 cents for every dollar it gave to the federal government. This "permanent 15-cent deficit," she explained, was one reason among many that the city had trouble completing major transportation projects.
“For big projects like the Second Avenue subway,” she wrote, “the federal funds we get are bought with our own money and then some."
New York City is not an aberration. A 2009 report by the New York Times on President Obama’s stimulus bill determined that the 100 largest metro areas were getting less than half of the transportation money, despite compiling two-thirds of the national population and an even larger share of economic output.
Yet this underlies a longtime trend, in which states of largely rural and suburban character get more federal funding per tax dollar paid than urban ones. It is particularly pronounced for transportation funding, says University of Michigan economist David Albouy. He determined that states represented by Republicans—aka states with lower densities—receive more in federal transportation grants. Another study in 2009 by Boise State University found that for the federal Highway Trust Fund, “states that are less urban and better represented on the four key Congressional committees generally benefit from redistribution.”
The reason why is no mystery: urban areas generate higher incomes, meaning they are taxed more per capita, only to see that money funneled into poorer rural areas. It is also due to a political system that grants senatorial representation--and electoral votes--based on state lines, rather than on a per capita basis. This guarantees that funding will not be divided per capita, either. And again, this is namely so for transportation, which is often funded through a pork-barrel process that puts a premium on political influence.
So if we continue funneling money to the federal government for transportation, these economic and political factors will ensure that it goes disproportionately to states with lower incomes, densities, and populations...and away from major cities.
But this isn’t the only way the federal government hurts cities' transportation capabilities. The Davis-Bacon Act requires that prevailing wages are paid on federal construction projects; and President Obama signed an executive order mandating that Project Labor Agreements - or prearranged union deals - be used for all federal contracts exceeding $25 million. Both have been found to increase construction costs. The federal government also imposes various environmental and aesthetic requirements as a condition for funding, which, again, increases costs and slows the approval process.
Indeed, the very structure of modern federal transportation policy is hardwired towards inefficiency, whether for big cities or small, and Republican or Democratic states. The federal government collects taxpayer money from the local level (generally through the gas tax), and sends it to various federal agencies and politically-driven congressional legislators, who send it back to where it came from, with a new, more onerous set of guidelines. How is this better than if localities just kept their transportation money? It isn't: one Heritage Foundation study found that since the federal gas tax was implemented in 1956, 28 states suffered a negative return ratio on the money they put in.
The second problem with federalizing transportation policy is that often the projects that get built prove arbitrary and insensitive to local needs. The track record on this dates back to post-WWII urban renewal, when federal funds were used to ram highways through cohesive city neighborhoods. This has continued over the years with a wide range of federally-funded boondoggles: the Detroit people mover that moves no people; the bridge to nowhere in Alaska (a remote, sparsely-populated state that gets by far the highest gas tax return ratio); and the California high speed rail that will begin by linking the strategic corridor of Fresno with some place called Madera.
Such misallocations continue today through the Highway Trust Fund, which mandates that portions of gas tax revenue get spent on bike paths and other alternative transit, whether or not this is needed in given areas. The folly of this one-size-fits-all blueprint was unwittingly summarized by Congressman Earl Blumenauer. He once complained to Streetsblog.org that certain southern Congressman were thwarting his attempts to get more bike lane funding into a transportation bill. Of course, Blumenauer represents Portland, a relatively dense city where bike lanes are popular and useful. He was sparring with congressman in rural states like Georgia, where bike lanes are largely pointless. It's absurd that congressmen from either area would try imposing their visions on one another, since they are representing wildly different areas. Yet this uniform, top-down paradigm defines modern federal transportation policy.
On that note, I'd encourage this group of Congressional staffers to embrace a more local approach to transportation. This could include advocating for a "block grant" model, where the federal government sends money to state and local governments with less strings attached. Or it could include the sounder - if less politically likely - approach of just reducing the size and role of federal transportation agencies. That way localities - namely big cities - could keep more money for themselves.
[This article has been modified and updated from a Capitol Hill briefing I gave for the Cato Institute. You can watch the full speech here.]
Scott Beyer owns and manages The Market Urbanist.
Market Urbanist is a media company that advances free-market city policy. We aim for a liberalized approach that produces cheaper housing, faster transport and better quality-of-life.